CHAPTER ONE
The Political Foundations of
Booty Capitalism in the Philippines
States are not standardized commodities. They come in a wide array of sizes, shapes, and
styles. That incumbents sometimes use the state apparatus to extract and distribute
unproductive rents is undeniable. That all states perform certain functions indispensable to
economic transformation is equally so. That both characteristics are randomly distributed
across states is very unlikely, yet we have only a hazy sense of the range of variation, to
say nothing of its causes.
-Peter Evans, "Predatory, Developmental, and Other Apparatuses: A Com-
parative Political Economy Perspective on the Third World State," 1989
In the reality of political systems, patrimonial and legal elements are mixed, though all
societies have patrimonial traces while some have only a few legal ones.
-Daniel S. Lev, "Judicial Authority and the
Struggle for an Indonesian Rechtsstaat," 1978
A scholar of the Philippines once noted that "business is born, and
flourishes or fails, not so much in the market place as in the halls of the
legislature or in the administrative offices of the government. " Although
this observation was made in 1959, it could have been repeated with equal
validity in subsequent decades. Whether in the pre-martial law years
( 1946-1972), martial law years ( 1972-1986), or post-Marcos years (after
1986), one finds remarkable continuity in basic patterns of interaction
between the Philippine state and dominant economic interests. Even as it
is often incapable of meeting even the most basic infrastructural needs of
the economy, the Philippine state is nonetheless central to any compre-
hensive analysis of the country's political economy. Access to the state
apparatus has been the major avenue to private accumulation, as the quest
for "rent-seeking" opportunities brings a stampede of favored elites and
would-be favored elites to the gates of Malacaiiang Palace. The state appa-
ratus has repeatedly been choked by an anarchy of particularistic demands
from, and particularistic actions on behalf of, those oligarchs and cronies
who are currently most favored by its top officials: one will obtain a highly
coveted loan or import license, another will enjoy a stake in a cartelized
industry protected by highly discretionary state regulations.
Because of the weak institutionalization of the state, the personal favor
and disfavor of those currently in power is a critical determinant of busi-
ness success and failure. Political administration in the Philippines is often
treated as a personal affair, and one can find many parallels between the
modern Philippine polity and Weber's description of patrimonial states:
"In general, the notion of an objectively defined official duty is unknown to
the office that is based purely upon personal relations of subordina-
tion .... Instead of bureaucratic impartiality and of the ideal-based on
the abstract validity of one objective law for all-of administrating without
respect of persons, the opposite principle prevails. Practically everything
depends explicitly upon the personal considerations: upon the attitude
toward the concrete applicant and his concrete request and upon purely
personal connections, favors, promises, and privileges. " It is not enough
to say that the state lacks significant autonomy and capacity; in fact, to
paraphrase Weber, the conceptual separation of the state from all personal
authority of individuals is often remote from Philippine "structures of
authority. "
While all states possess patrimonial features to some degree, it is clear
that there is a particularly large gap between the Philippine state and the
archetypal bureaucratic state. The patrimonial framework helps us to
Booty Capitalism: The Politics of Banking in the Philippines by Paul D. Hutchcroft