Types of market-oriented environmental tools

0
7K

Key points

  • The three main categories of market-oriented environmental policies are pollution charges, marketable permits, and better-defined property rights.
  • marketable permit program is a program in which a city or state government issues permits allowing only a certain quantity of pollution. These permits to pollute can be sold or given to firms free.
  • pollution charge is a tax imposed on the quantity of pollution that a firm emits.
  • Property rights are the legal rights of ownership on which others are not allowed to infringe without paying compensation.

Three types of market-oriented environmental tools

There are three main categories of market-oriented environmental tools: pollution charges, marketable permits, and better-defined property rights.
In this article, we'll look at each of these tools in depth.

Pollution charges

pollution charge is a tax imposed on the quantity of pollution that a firm emits. A pollution charge gives a profit-maximizing firm an incentive to figure out ways to reduce its emissions—as long as the marginal cost of reducing the emissions is less than the tax.
For example, consider a small firm that emits 50 pounds per year of small particles, such as soot, into the air. Particulate matter, as it is called, causes respiratory illnesses and also imposes costs on firms and individuals.
The graph below illustrates the marginal costs that a firm faces in reducing pollution. The marginal cost of pollution reduction, like most marginal cost curves increases with output, at least in the short run. Reducing the first 10 pounds of particulate emissions costs the firm $300. Reducing the second 10 pounds would cost $500. The third ten pounds would cost $900, the fourth 10 pounds $1,500, and the fifth 10 pounds $2,500. This pattern for the costs of reducing pollution is common—the firm can use the cheapest and easiest method to make initial reductions in pollution, but additional reductions in pollution become more expensive.
 
 
Imagine the firm now faces a pollution tax of $1,000 for every 10 pounds of particulates emitted. The firm has the choice of either polluting and paying the tax, or reducing the amount of particulates they emit and paying the cost of abatement as shown in the graph above.
How much will the firm pollute and how much will the firm abate? The first 10 pounds would cost the firm $300 to abate. This is substantially less than the $1,000 tax, so they will choose to abate. The second 10 pounds would cost $500 to abate, which is still less than the tax, so they will choose to abate. The third 10 pounds would cost $900 to abate, which is slightly less than the $1,000 tax. The fourth 10 pounds would cost $1,500, which is much more costly than paying the tax. As a result, the firm will decide to reduce pollutants by 30 pounds because the marginal cost of reducing pollution by this amount is less than the pollution tax. With a tax of $1,000, the firm has no incentive to reduce pollution more than 30 pounds.
A firm that has to pay a pollution tax will have an incentive to figure out the least expensive technologies for reducing pollution. Firms that can reduce pollution cheaply and easily will do so to minimize their pollution taxes, whereas firms that will incur high costs for reducing pollution will end up paying the pollution tax instead. If the pollution tax applies to every source of pollution, then no special favoritism or loopholes are created for politically well-connected producers.
For an example of a pollution charge at the household level, let's consider two ways of charging for garbage collection. One method is to have a flat fee per household, no matter how much garbage a household produces. An alternative approach is to have several levels of fees, depending on how much garbage the household produces and to offer lower or free charges for recyclable materials. As of 2006, the US Environmental Protection Agency had recorded over 7,000 communities that have implemented pay-as-you-throw programs. When people have a financial incentive to put out less garbage and to increase recycling, they find ways of doing so.
A number of environmental policies are really pollution charges, although they often do not travel under that name. For example, the federal government and many state governments impose taxes on gasoline. We can view this tax as a charge on the air pollution that cars generate as well as a source of funding for maintaining roads.
Similarly, the refundable charge of five or 10 cents that some states have for returning recyclable cans and bottles works like a pollution tax that provides an incentive to avoid littering or throwing bottles in the trash. Compared with command-and-control regulation, a pollution tax reduces pollution in a more flexible and cost-effective way.

Marketable permits

When a city or state government sets up a marketable permit program—for example, cap and trade—it must start by determining the overall quantity of pollution it will allow as it tries to meet national pollution standards. Then, a number of permits allowing only this quantity of pollution are divided among the firms that emit that pollutant. These permits to pollute can be sold or given to firms free.
Now, add two more conditions. Imagine that these permits are designed to reduce total emissions over time. For example, a permit may allow emission of 10 units of pollution one year, but only 9 units the next year, then 8 units the year after that, and so on down to some lower level. In addition, imagine that these are marketable permits, meaning that firms can buy and sell them.
To see how marketable permits can work to reduce pollution, consider the four firms listed in the table below. The table shows current emissions of lead from each firm. At the start of the marketable permit program, each firm receives permits to allow this level of pollution. However, these permits are shrinkable, and next year the permits allow the firms to emit only half as much pollution.
Let’s say that in a year, Firm Gamma finds it easy and cheap to reduce emissions from 600 tons of lead to 200 tons, which means that it has permits that it is not using that allow emitting 100 tons of lead. Firm Beta reduces its lead pollution from 400 tons to 200 tons, so it does not need to buy any permits, and it does not have any extra permits to sell. However, although Firm Alpha can easily reduce pollution from 200 tons to 150 tons, it finds that it is cheaper to purchase permits from Gamma rather than to reduce its own emissions to 100. Meanwhile, Firm Delta did not even exist in the first period, so the only way it can start production is to purchase permits to emit 50 tons of lead.
Search
Categories
Read More
Социальные проблемы
Шесть минут до полуночи. Six Minutes to Midnight. (2020)
Англия. Канун Второй мировой войны. Томас Миллер, учитель английского языка в Союзе немецких...
By Nikolai Pokryshkin 2022-10-08 21:01:36 0 14K
Addictions
Addiction: Causes, Effects, and Pathways to Recovery
Addiction is a complex, multifaceted condition characterized by compulsive engagement in...
By Dacey Rankins 2024-10-18 18:56:01 0 13K
Social Issues
The Usual Suspects. (1995),
A sole survivor tells of the twisty events leading up to a horrific gun battle on a boat, which...
By Leonard Pokrovski 2022-12-02 20:31:54 0 14K
Sport
Raging Bull. (1980)
The life of boxer Jake LaMotta, whose violence and temper that led him to the top in the ring...
By Leonard Pokrovski 2023-03-02 18:42:28 0 11K
Team Handball
Team Handball: The Fast-Paced Sport with Global Appeal
Team Handball: The Fast-Paced Sport with Global Appeal Team handball, often simply referred to...
By Leonard Pokrovski 2024-07-11 13:38:35 0 13K
image/svg+xml


BigMoney.VIP Powered by Hosting Pokrov