Shifts in aggregate supply
Сообщение 2 года назад
0
5Кб
Key points
-
The aggregate demand/aggregate supply model is a model that shows what determines total supply or total demand for the economy and how total demand and total supply interact at the macroeconomic level.
-
Movements of either the aggregate supply or aggregate demand curve in an AD/AS diagram will result in a different equilibrium output and price level.
-
The aggregate supply curve shifts to the right as productivity increases or the price of key inputs falls, making a combination of lower inflation, higher output, and lower unemployment possible.
-
The aggregate supply curve shifts to the left as the price of key inputs rises, making a combination of lower output, higher unemployment, and higher inflation possible.
-
When an economy experiences stagnant growth and high inflation at the same time it is referred to as stagflation.
Introduction
If either the aggregate supply or aggregate demand curve shifts in the aggregate demand/aggregate supply—AD/AS—model, the original equilibrium in the AD/AS diagram will shift to a new equilibrium.
If the aggregate supply—also referred to as the short-run aggregate supply or SRAS—curve shifts to the right, then a greater quantity of real GDP is produced at every price level. If the aggregate supply curve shifts to the left, then a lower quantity of real GDP is produced at every price level. In this article, we'll discuss two of the most important factors that can lead to shifts in the SRAS curve—productivity growth and input prices.
How productivity growth shifts the AS curve
In the long run, the most important factor shifting the SRAS curve is productivity growth. Productivity—in economic terms—is how much output can be produced with a given quantity of labor. One measure of this is output per worker, or GDP per capita.
Over time, productivity grows so that the same quantity of labor can produce more output. Historically, the real growth in GDP per capita in an advanced economy like the United States has averaged about 2% to 3% per year, but productivity growth has been faster during certain extended periods.
A higher level of productivity shifts the SRAS curve to the right because with improved productivity, firms can produce a greater quantity of output at every price level.
The two AD/AS diagrams below show shifts in productivity over two time periods. We'll start by looking at the first period—analyzed in Diagram A—where productivity increases, shifting the SRAS curve to the right from SRAS0SRAS0start text, S, R, A, S, 0, end text to SRAS1SRAS1start text, S, R, A, S, 1, end text to SRAS2SRAS2start text, S, R, A, S, 2, end text, reflecting the rise in potential GDP in this economy. The equilibrium shifts from E0E0start text, E, 0, end text to E1E1start text, E, 1, end text to E2E2start text, E, 2, end text.
A shift in the SRAS curve to the right results in a greater real GDP and downward pressure on the price level if aggregate demand remains unchanged. However, if this shift in SRAS results from gains in productivity growth, which are typically measured in terms of a few percentage points per year, the effect will be relatively small over a few months or even a couple of years.
We'll take a look at Diagram B, which deals with increases in input prices, in the next section.
How changes in input prices shift the AS curve
Higher prices for inputs that are widely used across the entire economy—for example, wages and energy products—can have a macroeconomic impact on aggregate supply.
Increases in the price of such inputs cause the SRAS curve to shift to the left, which means that at each given price level for outputs, a higher price for inputs will discourage production because it will reduce the possibilities for earning profits. Diagram B, on the right above, shows the aggregate supply curve shifting to the left, from SRAS0SRAS0start text, S, R, A, S, 0, end text to SRAS1SRAS1start text, S, R, A, S, 1, end text, which causes the equilibrium to move from E0E0start text, E, 0, end text to E1E1start text, E, 1, end text.
This movement from the original equilibrium of E0E0start text, E, 0, end text to the new equilibrium of E1E1start text, E, 1, end text brings a nasty set of effects: reduced GDP or recession, higher unemployment because the economy is now further away from potential GDP, and an inflationary higher price level as well. Take, for example, the US economic recessions in 1974–1975, 1980–1982, 1990–91, 2001, and 2007–2009—each was preceded or accompanied by a rise in the key input of oil prices. In the 1970s, this pattern of a shift to the left in SRAS leading to a stagnant economy with high unemployment and inflation was nicknamed stagflation.
On the other hand, a decline in the price of a key input like oil will shift the SRAS curve to the right, providing an incentive for more to be produced at every given price level for outputs. From 1985 to 1986, for example, the average price of crude oil fell by almost half, from $24 a barrel to $12 a barrel. Similarly, from 1997 to 1998, the price of a barrel of crude oil dropped from $17 per barrel to $11 per barrel. In both cases, the plummeting price of oil led to a situation like that presented in Diagram A, on the left above, where the shift of the SRAS curve to the right allowed the economy to expand, unemployment to fall, and inflation to decline.
Along with energy prices, two other key inputs that may shift the SRAS curve are the cost of labor, or wages, and the cost of imported goods that are used as inputs for other products. In these cases as well, the lesson is that lower prices for inputs cause SRAS to shift to the right, while higher prices cause it to shift back to the left.
Other supply shocks
The aggregate supply curve can also shift due to shocks to input goods or labor. For example, an unexpected early freeze could destroy a large number of agricultural crops—a shock that would shift the SRAS curve to the left since there would be fewer agricultural products available at any given price.
Similarly, shocks to the labor market can affect aggregate supply. An extreme example would be an overseas war that requires a large number of workers to cease their ordinary production in order to go fight for their country. In this case, aggregate supply would shift to the left because there would be fewer workers available to produce goods at any given price.
Summary
-
The aggregate demand/aggregate supply model is a model that shows what determines total supply or total demand for the economy and how total demand and total supply interact at the macroeconomic level.
-
Movements of either the aggregate supply or aggregate demand curve in an AD/AS diagram will result in a different equilibrium output and price level.
-
The aggregate supply curve shifts to the right as productivity increases or the price of key inputs falls, making a combination of lower inflation, higher output, and lower unemployment possible.
-
The aggregate supply curve shifts to the left as the price of key inputs rises, making a combination of lower output, higher unemployment, and higher inflation possible.
-
When an economy experiences stagnant growth and high inflation at the same time it is referred to as stagflation.
Поиск
Категории
- Arts
- Business
- Computers
- Игры
- Health
- Главная
- Kids and Teens
- Деньги
- News
- Recreation
- Reference
- Regional
- Science
- Shopping
- Society
- Sports
- Бизнес
- Деньги
- Дом
- Досуг
- Здоровье
- Игры
- Искусство
- Источники информации
- Компьютеры
- Наука
- Новости и СМИ
- Общество
- Покупки
- Спорт
- Страны и регионы
- World
Больше
Dyslexia: Gene–environment interaction
The contribution of gene–environment interaction to reading disability has been intensely...
Python Spotipy
Spotipy is a lightweight Python library for the Spotify Web API. With Spotipy you...
Страсти Жанны д'Арк. The Passion of Joan of Arc. (1928)
1431 год. Жанна д`Арк предстает перед судом по обвинению в ереси.
Отец. The Father. (2020)
Энтони уже далеко не молод и живет один в лондонской квартире. Он считает, что прекрасно...